Is Estonia a sign of what’s to come for the euro?
The most significant EU-related development over the holidays was Estonia’s official entry into the eurozone on New Year’s Day, an event that is worth revisiting as the single currency prepares for what is likely to be another year of turmoil.
As Fredrik Erixon, director of the Brussels-based European Centre for International Political Economy, notes in a new “Obituary for the Estonian kroon”, it wasn’t too long ago that the Estonian government was being advised to drop its peg to the euro and let its currency float in order to save its economy from the ravages of the European debt crisis.
But Tallinn hung tough, and as we noted in an article last month, is now poised for gross domestic product growth that is the pride of the EU. According to forecasts by Eurostat, its 4.4 per cent 2011 real GDP growth would make it the best performer in the eurozone.
When I talked to Estonian President Toomas Hendrik Ilves last month, he recalled with hard-to-contain smugness the amount of pressure the country resisted to devalue during the early days of the euro crisis. “All three Baltic economies were in serious trouble, and all kinds of people said devalue, devalue, devalue,” he said.
In his paper, Erixon cites U.S.-baed economic giants like Paul Krugman and Nouriel Roubini as among those who advocated devaluation, but officials recently told me that the International Monetary Fund was also in the Baltic devaluation camp.
Ilves argued that devaluation, even for an export-reliant economy, wasn’t a panacea. It could have reduced the price of Estonian exports and relative labour costs, he said, but because Estonia imported so many of the components that go into its exports, the gains would be marginal.
In addition, Ilves argued, Estonian home mortgages and commercial loans were largely denominated in euros. So a devaluation would have sent borrowing costs skyrocketing.
“You decapitate all those who are doing the right thing,” he said. “You’re doing in the people who are the most successful, the most economically active, the people who are doing what you want them to be doing.”
Instead, Estonia cut budgets early and deeply. Does the fact that it is now poised for a rebound bode well for other recent takers of the austerity medicine, like Greece, Ireland, Spain and Portugal? Perhaps, but the Estonians also had a few things going for them that these others – particularly Portugal and Greece – do not: an open, competitive economy and crucially, in the view of Ilves, a reserve fund that carried them through the rough times.
“We resisted the populist pressure in the good years to go and spend the reserves, and we went into the recession with strong reserves which tides us over,” he said. Other Baltics, particularly Latvia, which was forced to rely on an international bailout, were less cautious.
As a new member of the eurozone, Ilves said Estonia was ready to play its part in helping the countries who have fared less well during the recent crisis. Even though it is small and comparatively poor, Ilves said his country is well aware of what shared responsibility means – as a new member of NATO, he noted, Estonia relies on the alliance’s defence guarantees, which allows Tallinn to save more than a bit on military spending.
But if there’s one thing the euro’s 17th member won’t tolerate, he said, it’s a lecture. Here, I’ll just let Ilves speak for himself:
The poorer countries that are fiscally responsible end up paying out richer countries that are not. This would be even ok except for the occasional arrogance and haughtiness of the rich countries towards us poor east Europeans. You can’t be haughty towards us because we’re not so rich, and at the same time [argue] it’s time to bail them out. Ultimately, let’s face it: Being richer wasn’t based on being more productive. It was based on bigger loans. Wealth based on loans is not wealth.
Estonia could prove an interesting new voice in the deabte over the single currency’s future.
“Wealth based on loans is not wealth.”
Loans are denominated in the official money units.
Owning wealth aside from official money units is the only way
by which societies have built up their storehouse of a wealth of things,
thereby advancing their kind from the beginning, and preventing the decapitation of all those who are doing the right thing.
Estonia will do well in the eurozone for two reasons: it is small, and it is still an emerging market. By definition, emerging markets have a lot of catch up to do, therefore they must invest more in capital goods to become a capital-intensive economy (than a labor-intensive economy). By using more machinery and other capital, while also making substantial infrastructure improvements, cost per productivity would sharply fall. This would make them even more competitive than mature economies like Germany or Finland.
In other words, as a nation developes, its currency should appreciate in value (like China's should). By Estonia joining the euro, it would put a cap any upward pressure on its own currency, the Kroon -- by joining the euro, it would be in a currency bloc with mature economies that do not see significant upward pressure on exchange rates. Estonia, then would be playing beggar-thy-neighbor policies. A good template for Estonia is Slovakia, which has seen its unit labor costs decline throughout the past decade in relation to Germany (Spain and others saw their unit labor costs rise against Germany). Such "competitive" Eastern economies in the euro would make it even harder for Spain or Greece to compete. Report Derek Tunnicliffe
One of the lessons that Estonia might offer to others countries (inside and outside the eurozone) is that of their "flat-rate" tax system. It was untried experiment when they took it on, but it appears to be a success, in both business and personal terms. But they also try to ensure a balanced governmental budget - another lesson for all but Germany?
As Fredrik Erixon, director of the Brussels-based European Centre for International Political Economy, notes in a new “Obituary for the Estonian kroon”, it wasn’t too long ago that the Estonian government was being advised to drop its peg to the euro and let its currency float in order to save its economy from the ravages of the European debt crisis.
But Tallinn hung tough, and as we noted in an article last month, is now poised for gross domestic product growth that is the pride of the EU. According to forecasts by Eurostat, its 4.4 per cent 2011 real GDP growth would make it the best performer in the eurozone.
When I talked to Estonian President Toomas Hendrik Ilves last month, he recalled with hard-to-contain smugness the amount of pressure the country resisted to devalue during the early days of the euro crisis. “All three Baltic economies were in serious trouble, and all kinds of people said devalue, devalue, devalue,” he said.
In his paper, Erixon cites U.S.-baed economic giants like Paul Krugman and Nouriel Roubini as among those who advocated devaluation, but officials recently told me that the International Monetary Fund was also in the Baltic devaluation camp.
Ilves argued that devaluation, even for an export-reliant economy, wasn’t a panacea. It could have reduced the price of Estonian exports and relative labour costs, he said, but because Estonia imported so many of the components that go into its exports, the gains would be marginal.
In addition, Ilves argued, Estonian home mortgages and commercial loans were largely denominated in euros. So a devaluation would have sent borrowing costs skyrocketing.
“You decapitate all those who are doing the right thing,” he said. “You’re doing in the people who are the most successful, the most economically active, the people who are doing what you want them to be doing.”
Instead, Estonia cut budgets early and deeply. Does the fact that it is now poised for a rebound bode well for other recent takers of the austerity medicine, like Greece, Ireland, Spain and Portugal? Perhaps, but the Estonians also had a few things going for them that these others – particularly Portugal and Greece – do not: an open, competitive economy and crucially, in the view of Ilves, a reserve fund that carried them through the rough times.
“We resisted the populist pressure in the good years to go and spend the reserves, and we went into the recession with strong reserves which tides us over,” he said. Other Baltics, particularly Latvia, which was forced to rely on an international bailout, were less cautious.
As a new member of the eurozone, Ilves said Estonia was ready to play its part in helping the countries who have fared less well during the recent crisis. Even though it is small and comparatively poor, Ilves said his country is well aware of what shared responsibility means – as a new member of NATO, he noted, Estonia relies on the alliance’s defence guarantees, which allows Tallinn to save more than a bit on military spending.
But if there’s one thing the euro’s 17th member won’t tolerate, he said, it’s a lecture. Here, I’ll just let Ilves speak for himself:
The poorer countries that are fiscally responsible end up paying out richer countries that are not. This would be even ok except for the occasional arrogance and haughtiness of the rich countries towards us poor east Europeans. You can’t be haughty towards us because we’re not so rich, and at the same time [argue] it’s time to bail them out. Ultimately, let’s face it: Being richer wasn’t based on being more productive. It was based on bigger loans. Wealth based on loans is not wealth.
Estonia could prove an interesting new voice in the deabte over the single currency’s future.
“Wealth based on loans is not wealth.”
Loans are denominated in the official money units.
Owning wealth aside from official money units is the only way
by which societies have built up their storehouse of a wealth of things,
thereby advancing their kind from the beginning, and preventing the decapitation of all those who are doing the right thing.
Estonia will do well in the eurozone for two reasons: it is small, and it is still an emerging market. By definition, emerging markets have a lot of catch up to do, therefore they must invest more in capital goods to become a capital-intensive economy (than a labor-intensive economy). By using more machinery and other capital, while also making substantial infrastructure improvements, cost per productivity would sharply fall. This would make them even more competitive than mature economies like Germany or Finland.
In other words, as a nation developes, its currency should appreciate in value (like China's should). By Estonia joining the euro, it would put a cap any upward pressure on its own currency, the Kroon -- by joining the euro, it would be in a currency bloc with mature economies that do not see significant upward pressure on exchange rates. Estonia, then would be playing beggar-thy-neighbor policies. A good template for Estonia is Slovakia, which has seen its unit labor costs decline throughout the past decade in relation to Germany (Spain and others saw their unit labor costs rise against Germany). Such "competitive" Eastern economies in the euro would make it even harder for Spain or Greece to compete. Report Derek Tunnicliffe
One of the lessons that Estonia might offer to others countries (inside and outside the eurozone) is that of their "flat-rate" tax system. It was untried experiment when they took it on, but it appears to be a success, in both business and personal terms. But they also try to ensure a balanced governmental budget - another lesson for all but Germany?
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment